SR1. The value of y, for each value of x, is
y= ß_{1}+ß_{2}x+µ
SR2. The expected value of the random error µ is
E(µ)=0
which is equivalent to assuming
E(y)= ß_{1}+ß_{2}x
SR3. The variance of the random error µ is
var(µ)=sigma^2 = var(y)
The random variables y and µ have the same variance because they differ only by a constant.
SR4. The covariance between any pair of random errors µ_{i} and µ_{j} is
cov(µ_{i}, µ_{j})=cov(y_{i},y_{j})=0
SR5. The variable x is not random and must take at least two different values.
SR6. The values of µ are normally distributed about their mean
µ ~ N(0, sigma^2)
if the y values are normally distributed and vice-versa
Sunday, January 1, 2012
Monetary Policy & Credit Easing pt. 7: R Econometrics Tests
Friday, December 30, 2011
Monetary Policy & Credit Easing pt. 5: Explanatory Variables Continued...
WE will need to account for things other than the Fed that influenced risk premia as they relate to Treasury supply. The following three variables are meant to accomplish such a thing:
1. Federal Reserves holdings of total public debt as a percentage of GDP
2. Total government holdings of domestic credit market debt as a percentage of the total
3. Foreign holdings of government debt as a percentage of total public debt
1. Fed's holdings of total public debt as a percentage of GDP
Federal Reserve holdings of total public debt as a percentage of GDP is important because it controls for how much Federal Government support the Fed is accounting for. It is especially pertinent to our second estimation as the Feds holdings of total public debt relative to GDP increased sharply. Operationally, we define this variable as:
FedGDP_{t}= {GovDebt_{t}^{Fed}\ GDP_{t}}x 100
Where,
GovDebt_{t}^{Fed}=Federal Debt Held by Federal Reserve Banks (FDHBFRBN) at time, t
GDP_{t} = Gross Domestic Product, 1 Decimal (GDP) at time, t
We expect that this variable will move in line with both short-term and long-term risk premiums. Therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
Data Issues
The time-series necessary for this variable is provided by FRED and the details are as listed:
(a) Federal Debt Held by Federal Reserve Banks (FDHBFRBN), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1970-01-01 to 2011-0
(b) Gross Domestic Product, 1 Decimal (GDP), Quarterly, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate, 1947-01-01 to 2011-07-01
2. Government Holdings Of Domestic Credit Market Debt As A Percentage Of The Total
It would be wise to include a variable that account for fiscal policies support of the financial markets. This we can define as Federal Government holdings of credit market assets as a percentage of the total outstanding. To account for total government support of the financial markets we will use the following variable: govcredit.
govcredit_{t}={ CAssets_{t}^{Gov}\ CAssets_{t}^{Total} }x 100
Where,
CAssets_{t}^{Gov} = Total Credit Market Assets Held by Domestic Nonfiancial Sectors - Federal Government (FGTCMAHDNS) at time, t
CAssets_{t}^{Total} = Total Credit Market Assets Held by Domestic Nonfiancial Sectors (TCMAHDNS) at time, $t$
We expect that this variable will reduce both short-term and long-term risk premiums. Therefore:
H0: ß ≥ 0 vs. Ha: ß < 0
Data Issues
The time-series necessary for this variable is provided by FRED and the details are as listed:
(a) Total Credit Market Assets Held by Domestic Nonfiancial Sectors - Federal Government (FGTCMAHDNS), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1949-10-01 to 2011-04-01
(b) Total Credit Market Assets Held by Domestic Nonfiancial Sectors (TCMAHDNS), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1949-10-01 to 2011-04-01
3. Foreign Holdings of Federal Debt As A Percentage Of The Total
This variable labeled ForeignDebt_{t} seeks to capture the impact that foreign holdings of United States government debt have on both short-term and long-term risk premia. Theory would suggest that as foreign holdings go up risk-premia would go down. Operationally this variable is defined as follows:
ForeignDebt_{t} = {GovDebt_{t}^{Foreign}\ total public debt_{t}} x 100
Where,
GovDebt_{t}^{Foreign}= Federal Debt Held by Foreign & International Investors (FDHBFIN) at time, t
total public debt_{t}= Federal Government Debt: Total Public Debt (GFDEBTN) at time, t
Our ß coefficient on this variable is expected to be negative for both short-term and long-term risk premia and therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≥ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß < 0
Data Issues
The following data comes from FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) Federal Debt Held by Foreign & International Investors (FDHBFIN), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1970-01-01 to 2011-04-01
(b) Federal Government Debt: Total Public Debt (GFDEBTN), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1966-01-01 to 2011-04-01
We include two variables to help account for cyclicality in the overall economy. Both are relevant as the Fed uses these variables in its decision making process. For example in setting the federal funds rate, the Fed is said to have used a Taylor Rule that incorporated both the output gap and unemployment gap in its objective function. Thus incorporating these variables may present a problem of endogeneity over a short-part of our sample(like when a taylor-rule was said to be used), but these effects we will choose to ignore. The two cyclical variables we shall use are the output gap and the unemployment gap. The output gap is defined,
OGAP_{t}= Potential GDP_{t} – GDP_{t} at time, t
Where,
Potential GDP_{t}=Nominal Potential Gross Domestic Product (NGDPPOT) at time, t
GDP_{t}=Gross Domestic Product, 1 Decimal (GDP) at time, t
Our unemployment gap is defined in a similar fashion:
UGAP_{t}= NROU_{t} – UNRATE_{t} at time, t
Where,
NROU_{t}= Natural Rate of Unemployment (NROU) at time, t
UNRATE_{t}= Civilian Unemployment Rate (UNRATE) at time, t
Theoretically we assume that over the long-run as both of these variables increase the long-term risk premia increase. Over the short-run regressions we would expect these variables to have almost no significant effect as that time period is cluttered with many short-term things impacting risk-premia. Additionally for the short-term risk premia we would expect either a negative relationship or no relationship. This is because many things that impact the long-term risk premia one way have an opposite sign with respect to the short-term risk premia.
Data Issues
The data for these cyclical variables is provided by FRED and their details are laid out as follows:
(a) Civilian Unemployment Rate (UNRATE), Monthly, Seasonally Adjusted, 1948-01-01 to 2011-10-01
(b) Natural Rate of Unemployment (NROU), Quarterly, 1949-01-01 to 2021-10-01
(c) Nominal Potential Gross Domestic Product (NGDPPOT), Quarterly, 1949-01-01 to 2021-10-01
(d) Gross Domestic Product, 1 Decimal (GDP), Quarterly, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate, 1947-01-01 to 2011- 07-01
The next post gets into the R analysis and lays out our model in full.
Thursday, December 29, 2011
Monetary Policy & Credit Easing pt. 4: More Independent Variable Definitions
This variable will account for the Federal Reserves support of Depository Institutions through direct lending to these institutions. Support will be measured by how much the Fed made up for any shortfalls in Depository Institutions main source of cash- time and savings deposits. Federal Reserve support for our first estimation period is operationalized as follows:
Support_{t}={TotalBorrowingFed^{DI}_{t}\ Total Time & Savings Deposits_{t}^{DI}}x 100
Where,
Support_{t}= Fed funds at depository institutions as a percentage of their main financing streams (total savings and time deposits) at time, t
TotalBorrowingFed^{DI}_{t}= Total Borrowings of Depository Institutions from the Federal Reserve (BORROW) at time, t
Total Time & Savings Deposits_{t}^{DI}= Total Time and Savings Deposits at All Depository Institutions (TOTTDP) at time, t
For our second estimation period from 4/1/01 to 4/1/11 we will use a different variable that excludes time-deposits as the series that we would ideally like to use above was discontinued in 2006.
Support_{t}={TotalBorrowingFed^{DI}_{t}\ Total Savings Deposits_{t}^{DI}}x 100
Where,
Support_{t}= Fed funds at depository institutions as a percentage of their main financing stream (total saving deposits) at time, t
TotalBorrowingFed^{DI}_{t}= Total Borrowings of Depository Institutions from the Federal Reserve (BORROW) at time, t
Total Savings Deposits_{t}^{DI}= Total Savings Deposits at all Depository Institutions (WSAVNS) at time, t
The expected beta coefficient should be positively related to short-term risk premia, as tighter credit conditions require Depository Institutions to go to the Fed for help. Only after the risk-premia goes up and these institutions have no where else to go do they borrow from the Fed at the discount rate.
We expect the effect of lending support to depository institutions to be positively related to short-term risk premia, therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
Furthermore, we expect Fed support to depository institutions to have a negative effect on long-term risk premia because of the expectations component. As the Fed steps in with lending support, markets calm their fears about the future. This is directly the opposite of short-term risk premia as the support in that situation is in direct response to the risk premia. Therefore,
H_{0}: ß ≥ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß < 0
Data Issues
The following time-series data were provided by FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) Total Borrowings of Depository Institutions from the Federal Reserve (BORROW), Monthly, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1919-01-01 to 2011-10-01
(b) Total Savings Deposits at all Depository Institutions (WSAVNS), Weekly, Ending Monday, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1980-11-03 to 2011-10-17
(c) Total Time and Savings Deposits at All Depository Institutions (DISCONTINUED SERIES) (TOTTDP), Monthly, Seasonally Adjusted, 1959-01-01 to 2006-02-01
The motivation behind putting the Federal Funds rate into our regression model is simple. This is the main policy tool that the Fed has used to manipulate short-term credit conditions and influence the rate of inflation. The Fed controls this rate in hopes of influencing other rates such as the Prime Bank Loan Rate along with other short term credit instruments like Commercial Paper. Additionally, this variable is very easy to account for because it requires virtually zero manipulation. Notationally we will define it in the following manner:
FF_{t}= Federal Funds rate at time, t
The expected beta coefficient should be positively related to the short-term risk premia and negatively related to long-term risk premia. They theory is that by lowering the federal funds rate, or the rate at which banks lend to each other, the Fed is encouraging banks to lend and thus ease credit conditions. When the Fed feels that tightening is appropriate, maybe the result of a jump in inflation expectations or an deep acceleration in the economy, they respond by raising the federal funds rate. This tightens credit conditions and thus theoretically at least, should result in an increase in short-term risk premia. The opposite holds true for the federal funds rate effect on long-term risk premia. Since long-term rates are a function of shorter-term rates, investors are inclined to sell Treasuries which decreases the spread between Aaa and 10 year nominal treasuries, therefore decreasing long-term risk premia.
For short-term risk premiums we expect the federal funds rate to be positively related:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
For long-term risk premiums we expect the federal funds rate to be negativity related:
H_{0}: ß ≥ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß < 0
Data Issues
We get the series for the federal funds rate from FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) Effective Federal Funds Rate (FF), Weekly, Ending Wednesday, 1954-07-07 to 2011-10-19
This variable is also easy to account for because the introduction of interest paid on reserves has a direct impact on the physical quantity of excess reserves of depository institutions held at the Federal Reserve. The motivation behind this variable is that banking institutions would not hold excess reserves with the Fed without some compensation i.e. that opportunity cost has to be greater than zero. That is where the interest paid on excess reserves come in. Without it there is an opportunity cost of letting the reserves sit with the fed instead of seeking more profitable safe havens for their cash. That is why we will be using the quantity of excess reserves as our explanatory variable and notationally defining it as follows:
ER_{t}= Excess Reserves of Depository Institutions at time, t
When the Fed initiated its policy of paying interest on reserves it created an incentive for banks to shore up their finances with the Fed. It gave the Fed a way to conduct large scale asset purchases without suffering inflationary consequences. As long as the reserves are held with the Fed, they cannot be inflationary therefore an increase in excess reserves at the Fed is contractionary. Additionally, since the Fed had not initiated the policy of paying interest on reserves until October of 2008 there was no incentive for banks to hold any excess reserve balances before then. That is why our two estimation periods must have two different hypothesis tests for this variable:
For our estimation covering the 4/1/71 to 7/1/97 time period the interest paid on excess reserves policy was non-existent and therefore:
H_{0}: ß = 0 vs. H_{a}: ß ≠ 0
In other words, we are looking to not reject the null hypothesis that beta is equal to zero.
For our second estimation covering the 4/1/01 to 4/1/11 time period the interest paid on excess reserves policy was in effect, if only for a short-time before the end of the sample and therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
Data Issues
We get the series from FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) Excess Reserves of Depository Institutions (EXCRESNS), Monthly, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1959-01-01 to 2011-09-01
We must account for changes in the risk premia that aren't necessarily related to monetary policy. These include things like market fear, corporate default risk and controlling for changes due to underlying fundamentals like Corporate Profits After Tax.
The motivation behind including the yield curve is due to its known predictive power of economic growth and recessionary risk. As recessionary risk increase investors are more likely to put their funds into the safest assets with the highest return. Historically, this involves the purchase of longer-term Treasuries as they have zero default risk. When a bond is purchased its price goes up, and its effective yield decreases so the slope of the yield curve or the spread between the most liquid and shortest maturity bond and the most liquid, longest maturity bond decreases or flattens. As this slope flattens we expect risk premia to increase for longer maturity and less liquid debt instruments. As the yield curve flattens we expect T-bills to be sold and longer-term Treasuries to be purchased. This puts upward pressure on T-bill rates, thus narrowing the spread between Commercial Paper and T-bills and reducing the short-term risk premia.
The yield curve as we define it is the spread between the 10-Year Nominal Treasury Note rate and the 3-Month Nominal Secondary Market Treasury Bill rate. Notationally,
YC_{t}=GS10_{t} – TB3MS_{t}
Where,
YC_{t}= Yield curve at time, t
GS10_{t}= 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate at time, t
TB3MS_{t}= 3-Month Treasury Bill: Secondary Market Rate at time, t
The beta coefficient for both of our estimation periods is expected to be negatively related to long-term risk premia. Therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≥ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß ≤ 0
The beta coefficient for both of our estimation periods is expected to be positively related to short-term risk premia. Therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
Data Issues
We get the two times-series data from FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate (GS10), Monthly, 1953-04-01 to 2011-09-01
(b) 3-Month Treasury Bill: Secondary Market Rate (TB3MS), Monthly, 1934-01-01 to 2011-09-01
We will control for market fear by including a measure of stock market volatility into our regression model. We define volatility as follows:
Volatility_{t}= CBOE DJIA Volatility Index (VXDCLS) at time, t
The motivation behind this control variable is that the returns from owning stocks become more volatile in times of fear. Thus the risk premia on assets that aren't risk free like corporate bonds may increase in response to this market volatility.
This variables is literally only relevant in the regression on long-term premiums for our second estimation period. We cannot reasonably assume it has any effect on short-term risk premia because stock market volatility signals the fear of financial markets which leads to flight to safety into longer term treasuries not short-term commercial paper. The reason is that an investor probably couldn't even have the capital to buy commercial paper to begin with and secondly when fear strikes investors tend to pour their capital into longer term treasuries because they can pick up some extra yield. This would widen the spread between Aaa and Treasuries thus increasing the risk premium. Therefore we include this variable only in our second estimation and its only real effect will be on the long-term risk premia.
For the regression over our second estimation period, increased volatility is expected to increase the long-term risk premium:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
For the regression over our second estimation period, volatility is not expected to have an effect on short-term risk premia, therefore:
H_{0}: ß = 0 vs. H_{a}: ß ≠ 0
In other words, we are looking to not reject the null hypothesis that $\beta$ is equal to zero.
Data Issues
We get the times-series data from FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) CBOE DJIA Volatility Index (VXDCLS), Daily, Close, 1997-10-07 to 2011-11-02
It would be prudent to control for the perceived credit default risk of the corporate bonds market. To do this we use the spread between the AAA and BAA rates bonds which would theoretically correspond to increased compensation for the risk of a default. The reason being we want to see how much the Fed's actions influence the risk premia and factor out movements in the spread that may incorporate other things like flat out default risk. Ideally we would like to use a Credit Default Swap Index to control for default risk as it would help us control directly for default risk and not other things like liquidity risk, but given the sample length data limitations we are forced to stick with what we've got.
The control variable we use for corporate default risk is the spread between Moody's rated Baa's and Aaa's. This is used because data exists for the full length of our desired samples and therefore is operationalized as follows:
Default^{spread}_{t}=BAA_{t} – AAA_{t}
Where,
BAA_{t}= Moody's Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond Yield at time, t
AAA_{t}= Moody's Seasoned Aaa Corporate Bond Yield at time, t
The beta coefficient on our corporate default control variable is expected to be positive in our regression on long-term rates since an increase in the spread between BAA and AAA would indicate that these bonds expected default risk would increase:
H_{0}: ß ≤ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß > 0
In our regressions on short-term risk premia, the expected effect of this control variable is effectively zero as this variable deals with longer-term interest rates not exactly pertinent to short-term financing like commercial paper or Treasury Bills:
H_{0}: ß = 0 vs. H_{a}: ß ≠ 0
In other words, we are looking to not reject the null hypothesis that $\beta$ is equal to zero.
Data Issues
For the AAA and BAA data we use FRED:
(a) Moody's Seasoned Aaa Corporate Bond Yield (AAA), Monthly, 1919-01-01 to 2011-09-01
(b) Moody's Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond Yield (BAA), Monthly, 1919-01-01 to 2011-09-01
As corporate profits after tax increase the risk premium on corporate bonds decrease. This fundamentally negative relationship should be controlled for in our regression model. Operationally, this is defined as:
CP_{t} = Corporate Profits After Tax at time, t
The beta coefficient on our CP control variable should be negatively related to our dependent variables. This is because as corporate profits after tax increase the risk that they will renege on their debt obligations will decrease. This gives us the following test.
H_{0}: ß ≥ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß < 0
Data Issues
We get the times-series data from FRED and the details are as follows:
(a) Corporate Profits After Tax (CP), Quarterly, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate, 1947-01-01 to 2011-04-01
Keep dancin'
Steven J.
Wednesday, December 28, 2011
Monetary Policy & Credit Easing pt. 3: Accounting For The Composition of The Fed's Balance Sheet & Credit Easing
Between December 2008 and March 2010, the Federal Reserve will have purchased more than $1.7 trillion in assets. This represents 22 percent of the $7.7 trillion stock of longer-term agency debt, fixed-rate agency MBS, and Treasury securities outstanding at the beginning of the LSAPs.
Monetary Policy & Credit Easing pt. 2: Defining Our Variables
First Dependent Variable: Short-term Risk Premium & Commercial Paper
Commercial Paper is an unsecured promissory note with a fixed maturity of 1 to 270 days. We will be focusing on 90 day Commercial Paper. Commercial Paper is a money-market security issued by large banks and corporations to get money to meet short term debt obligations, and is only backed by an issuing bank or corporation's promise to pay the face amount on the maturity date specified on the note. Since it is not backed by collateral, only firms with excellent credit ratings from a recognized rating agency will be able to sell their Commercial Paper at a reasonable price. Additionally, Commercial Paper rates increase with maturity so they also have a duration risk associated with the price they fetch in the market place. Since this type of security is typically considered pretty risk free and has virtually zero rollover risk its deviation from the three-month Treasury bill rate seems like an appropriate measure of the short-term risk premium. The 3 Month T-bill is used as our risk-free asset because it is considered to have zero default risk and is highly liquid. Moreover, T-bills are used for short-term financing purposes which makes its use very similar to that of Commercial Paper. The short-term risk premium is thus operationalized as follows:
SR^{premium}_{t}= CP3M_{t} – TB3MS_{t}
Where,
SR^{premium}_{t} = Short-term Risk Premium at time, t
CP3M_{t}= 3-Month Commercial Paper Rate at time, t
TB3MS_{t}=3-Month Treasury Bill: Secondary Market Rate at time, t
Data Issues
For the 3-Month Treasury Bill series we use the following from FRED:
(a) 3-Month Treasury Bill: Secondary Market Rate (TB3MS), Monthly, 1934-01-01 to 2011-09-01
The 3-Month Commercial paper series is unfortunately not so easy to deal with. For one the series stops in 1997 and breaks off into two separate time series:
(b) 3-Month Commercial Paper Rate (DISCONTINUED SERIES) (CP3M), Monthly, 1971-04-01 to 1997-08-01
The two separate series include the financial commercial paper rate and the non-financial commercial paper rate:
(c) 3-Month AA Financial Commercial Paper Rate (CPF3M), Monthly, 1997-01-01 to 2011-09-01
(d) 3-Month AA Nonfinancial Commercial Paper Rate (CPN3M), Monthly, 1997-01-01 to 2011-09-01
To reconcile these issues, we take the average of the two and use them for the estimation of the Fed's policies over the second time period.
Second Dependent Variable: Long-term Risk Premium For Corporate Debt
For our long-term risk premium we choose to employ the 10 year Treasury Note rate as our risk-free rate because it shares the full promise of repayment by the United States Government. Moody's Aaa rated securities aren't so lucky and therefore carry a risk premium associated with them. Although, the risk-premium for longer-term securities includes several things that are more acute under stress than our counterpart short-term risk premium. These include a heightened duration risk, liquidity risk and default risk. We would expect our estimation of monetary policy effects on this variable to be more accurate as it theoretically should fluctuate more in response to actions taken by the Federal Reserve. The long-term risk premium is defined as follows:
LR^{premium}_{t}= BAA_{t} – GS10_{t}
where,
LR^{premium}_{t} =Long-term Risk Premium at time, t
BAA_{t} =Moody's Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond Yield at time, t
GS10_{t} =10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate at time, t
Data Issues
All of the data here comes from FRED and there series details are listed as follows:
(a) Moody's Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond Yield (BAA), Monthly, 1919-01-01 to 2011-09-01
(b) 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate (GS10), Monthly, 1953-04-01 to 2011-09-01
Independent Variables: The Federal Reserve's Monetary Policy Toolbox
Our independent variables seek to capture the many tools the Federal Reserve can and has employed throughout its history. This includes capturing the effects of traditionally unorthodox tools such as the manipulation of both the size (known as quantitative easing) and the composition (known as credit easing) of the Fed's balance sheet as well as capturing the effect from our more well known tools like changing the federal funds rate. We will also seek to determine the effects of interest paid on reserves.
Accounting For The Size Of The Fed's Balance Sheet & Quantitative Easing
Our first and in the authors opinion most important independent variable seeks to capture the Fed's balance sheet effects on risk premiums. It will be defined as the Feds holdings of credit market assets as a percentage of the total amount of assets held. The more the Fed supports credit markets the larger this percentage will be. It captures the balance sheets size as a percentage of the total market balance sheet. It is available over both our sample time periods and is therefore of pinnacle convenience to our analysis. One special component of the balance sheet has been the holding of Treasury Securities. Before November of 2008, the Federal Reserve maintained a relatively small portfolio of between $700 billion and $800 billion in Treasury securities- an amount largely determined by the volume of dollar currency that was in circulation. In late November 2008 the Federal Reserve announced that it would purchase up to $600 billion of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS). In March 2009, it enlarged the program to include cumulative purchases of up to $1.75 trillion of agency debt, agency MBS, and longer-term Treasury securities. As mentioned previously, the use of the balance sheet for financial easing was initiated because the Federal Reserves main policy instrument, the federal funds rate had effectively reached the zero lower bound in late 2008.
Operationally we define this variables as:
FedBalance^{size}_{t}={CreditAssets^{Fed}_{t}\ CreditAssets_{t}^{total}}x 100
where,
FedBalance^{size}_{t}= the percentage of the total credit market assets the Fed owns at time, t
CreditAssets^{Fed}_{t}= Total Credit Market Assets Held by Domestic Financial Sectors - Monetary Authority (MATCMAHDFS) at time, t
CreditAssets_{t}^{total}= Total Credit Market Assets Held (TCMAH) at time, t
This variable is the percentage of the total credit market assets that the Fed holds. Its coefficient is meant to be negative so that as it increases market interest rate risk premiums decrease. It accounts for the effects of the size of the Fed's balance sheet. We expect this variable to have a negative effect on both short-term and long-term risk premia and therefore:
H_{0}: ß ≥ 0 vs. H_{a}: ß ≤ 0
Data issues
The data for this variable is available for extraction from FRED and are detailed as follows:
(a) Total Credit Market Assets Held (TCMAH), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1949-10-01 to 2011-04-01
(b) Total Credit Market Assets Held by Domestic Financial Sectors - Monetary Authority (MATCMAHDFS), Quarterly, End of Period, Not Seasonally Adjusted, 1949-10-01 to 2011-04-01
Tuesday, December 27, 2011
Monetary Policy & Credit Easing pt. 1: Background & Theoretical Considerations
Under that view (portfolio balance channel view), our (the Fed) asset holdings keep longer-term interest rates lower than otherwise by reducing the aggregate amount of risk that the private markets have to bear. In particular, by purchasing longer-term securities, the Federal Reserve removes duration risk from the market, which should help to reduce the term premium that investors demand for holding longer-term securities. That effect should in turn boost other asset prices, as those investors displaced by the Fed’s purchases would likely seek to hold alternative types of securities.
Monday, December 26, 2011
Monetary Policy and Credit Easing
Keep Dancing,
Steven J.
Sunday, June 20, 2010
Paying Interest On Excess Reserves: From Theory To Practice
Notice that interest paid on excess reserves (the blue diamond line) has been at .25% and how an increase (decrease) in effective federal funds rate (red line) relative to interest on reserves leads to decreasing opportunity cost (increasing opportunity cost) associated with holding those excess reserves. We have been observing that a decrease in the effective fed funds rate (relative to interest on excess reserves) leads to increased holdings of excess reserves (green line). Many economists believe (including myself) that this Federal Reserve tool has been a main reason for inflation being subdued.
Tuesday, June 15, 2010
Empire State Manufacturing Survey for June: Slightly Better?
Positive index number indicates that more respondents believe that the index will move higher than lower. A negative index number tells us that more respondents were expecting that variable to decrease than increase.
Things to notice when looking at the Empire State Manufacturing Survey:
1. General Business Conditions Index- where a positive index number is a sign that factory activity is strengthening. This index edged up slightly from 19.11 in May to 19.57 in June.
2. New Orders Diffusion Index- where a jump in new orders is a good sign that factories will keep on producing. We see a nice increase in new orders with the index rising from 14.3 in May to 17.53 in June.
3. Unfilled Orders- which measures how overburdened (or under burdened) manufacturers are. The larger the index number the more businesses may want to spend to expand production capacity to satisfy customers with snappier deliveries. We have seen a nice improvement here as this index went from -7.89 in May to -1.23 in June.
4. Prices Paid- because the first signs of inflation appears here as factories ultimately pass higher costs onto consumers. Keep in mind that the Fed monitors this section closely (price stability is part of the Federal Reserve's dual mandate). Inflation does not seem to be as eminent on the horizon as it was last month but input prices are still expected to increase as this index moved from 44.74 in May to 27.16 in June.
5. Prices Received- as these help to forecast changes in corporate earnings. There is little change here as the index moved slightly downward from 5.26 to 4.94.
6. Number of Employees- which is the earliest indicator available on labor conditions for the month. This is where you preview changes in manufacturing jobs that could be seen in the official employment situation report. Unfortunately we don't see the enthusiasm we saw last month in this indicator as it contracted from 22.37 in May to 12.38 in June. This means that more firms this month than last month will be looking at lowering their number of employees and reducing their search for new hires.
From the NY Fed:
"The Empire State Manufacturing Survey indicates that conditions for New York manufacturers improved in June. The general business conditions index edged up from its May level to 19.6, extending its string of positive readings to eleven months. The new orders and shipments indexes were also positive and higher than their May levels. The inventories index remained near zero for a second straight month, indicating that inventory levels were little changed."
Monday, June 14, 2010
You know what's not going to occur this June 23rd?
Follow around the Federal Reserve's Board of Governors and you get a sense that the Fed is making it blatently clear. From Chairman Bernanke's testimony to Congress:
"The latest economic projections of Federal Reserve Governors and Reserve Bank presidents, which were made near the end of April, anticipate that real gross domestic product (GDP) will grow in the neighborhood of 3-1/2 percent over the course of 2010 as a whole and at a somewhat faster pace next year. This pace of growth, were it to be realized, would probably be associated with only a slow reduction in the unemployment rate over time. In this environment, inflation is likely to remain subdued. "To begin with let us think about what the Fed is mandated by law to do (for a wonderful speech by Frederic S. Mishkin on this):
"to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates"This being said with the employment numbers so weak (with initial claims for unemployment insurance still around 456,000) and inflation not even poking its nasty head up to say hello, there is no way (by law) that the Federal Reserve will raise the Federal Funds rate. With long-term inflation expectations stable and a struggling labor market why in the world would the Fed raise the interest rate?
Maybe, some should argue, that the zero bound interest rate will cause global imbalances elsewhere as investors search for the greatest yield. This may lead to a rush of credit to fuel the next great bubble. This leads me down the road to a third possible mandate: Financial Stability. Financial stability is one thing, maximum employment and stable prices are certainly another. The traditional monetary policy interest rate policy is way too blunt to deal with asset price bubbles and other threats to our economy. So to deal with this problem, lets create a new mandate for the Fed. Clearly I am not the first person to reach this conclusion- having first read something about this back in November of 2009:
"When it comes to redesigning monetary policy, there is disagreement as to how this might best be accomplished. Wharton finance and economics professor Franklin Allen believes more checks and balances could be built into the Federal Reserve system. “We need to have a third mandate - - a financial stability mandate,” he said."An adaptive financial stability mandate would give the Fed power to monitor developments in the financial world and allow it to 'quickly' propose regulation to make the growth more balanced. I know this sounds a little far fetched but why not? If mortgage origination was such a rampant free for all, then why not have the Fed be alerted of the developments? The Fed could theoretically be allowed to step in to find gaps in the regulation and the private sector could help:
"A dynamic regulatory regime is most likely to be realized if it receives non-governmental perspectives on these changes. In addition to disclosing more data to investors and counterparties, exposing supervisory practices and policies to external assessment in a structured way can improve supervision. Such exposure could, for example, reduce the chances of regulators converging around a conventional wisdom that overlooks anomalous data."If the Fed is allowed to extend credit to failing firms then it should be allowed to adaptively regulate those same firms. For more on financial regulation, Daniel K.Tarullo of the Federal Reserves seems to be on the front lines.
Wednesday, June 9, 2010
Why I Keep The Beige Book Under My Pillow. . .
Home sales and construction picked up till the end of the Home Buyers Tax Credit which expired on April 30th, and coincidentally in May these areas have been reported as slowing. Lower rents have pointed as a reason for increasing leasing activity in New York, Philadelphia, Richmond, Kansas City, Dallas, and San Francisco. One noteworthy extract is that some districts cited concerns over the potential impact of the European fiscal crises on financial and business conditions. These districts reported a corresponding increase in uncertainty and financial market volatility.
A look at Cleveland's report (since Cincinnati is a local branch) reveals that demand by business for new loans remains weak sauce. However, some bankers commented that the lending environment is starting to grow more competitive. This is generally consistent with yesterdays release of the Small Business Optimism Index . On a positive note, a large majority of the contacts reported that inventories are now well balanced which reflects increased demand. Furthermore, the number of respondents who plan on additional spending during the second half of 2010 has increased "substantially" since the last report.
For some Gulf oil spill action, the Atlanta Feds district said that contacts indicated the potential impact on the tourism industry along the coast line of Louisiana, Mississippi, Alabama, and western Florida could be substantial:
"In some cases, vacation lodging cancellations have been replaced by bookings for clean up crews, laborers, and the National Guard."
Friday, June 4, 2010
Natural Rate of Interest and the New Keynesians
A typical New Keynesian model has firms engaged in Monopolistic Competition and prices are assumed to be sticky. This leads to the horizontal short-run aggregate supply curve so output is demand determined. Household's and firms are assumed to act rationally, which implies they form expectations rationally. Consumption and investment decisions cause output to be affected by the private sectors expectations of future interest rates and future values of the natural rate. This framework is in equilibrium when current and expected real rate gaps are zero, GDP and natural GDP are equal and the price level has no tendency to change. The only reason i like the idea of a natural rate of interest is because it can be used to explain how imperfections in the financial markets can impact the real economy. Various market imperfections (including risk premia and credit rationing due to asymmetric information, incomplete indexation, and expectational errors by market participants) cause the real rate to deviate from the natural rate leading to a misallocation of credit.
Thursday, June 3, 2010
Success of the Fed's Currency Swap Program

Tuesday, June 1, 2010
The dangers of financial liberalization
We can see this with a simple example:
“Company A” in Michigan's Upper Peninsula deals with the mining and production of copper and "company B" makes copper tubing. B buys copper from A at a set market price "P". Then say there is an unrelated debt crisis in the euro-zone that shakes up investor confidence in everything from bond markets, stock markets and commodities so that a sudden drop in the price of copper worldwide occurs. Company B who now has to pay the original market price P finds that they also have to charge less for their copper tubing. This is because the tubing price is based off of the current market price per pound plus some service markup. Not only did company B already order this copper from company A at price P but now they have to charge less than it cost them to purchase it thus leading to a potentially crippling loss.
I guess the lesson here is that without stable expectations we may suffer from further bankruptcies. One of the reasons that the Fed controls the price level so well is that they convince people that the price level will change by a set amount. Unfortunately it is extremely unrealistic to create a Fed for the stock market or commodities markets to ensure slow and rising asset inflation. Instead we have a bunch of profit seeking investors searching for the greatest yield. Goods and services are determined by supply and demand and the rest of the mark-up comes from expected inflation. When something get financially liberalized its price is no longer a function of the market conditions (supply/demand/mark-up) it becomes a function of continuously changing expectations.
A further example may help illustrate my point. Assume tv's get financially liberalized and people sell and buy tv's based off their expectations about others demand for tv's. We would see drastic changes in tv prices that would not necessarily reflect supply and demand as a dramatic fall or rise in the price of tv's would put electronics stores out of business or in business. Waves of optimism and pessimism might impact their prices while not necessarily reflecting the true cost of production and mark-up.
Saturday, May 29, 2010
For the opposite view...
Furthermore, they dispute the often heard claim that deficit spending today burdens our grandchildren:
"in reality we leave them with government bonds that represent net financial assets and wealth. If the decision is made to raise taxes and retire the bonds in, say, 2050, the extra taxes are matched by payments made directly to bondholders in 2050”
Today's deficit leads to debt that must be retired later, and future tax increases that are supposed to service tomorrow's debt represent a redistribution from taxpayers to bondholders.
A government deficit is a transfer of income from the government to the private sector in the form of non-government income.
"A government deficit generates a net injection of disposable income into the private sector that increases saving and wealth, which can be held either in the form of government liabilities (cash or Treasuries) or noninterest-earning bank liabilities (bank deposits). If the nonbank public prefers bank deposits, then banks will hold an equivalent quantity of reserves, cash, and Treasuries (government IOUs), distributed according to bank preferences."
"A government budget surplus has exactly the opposite effect on private sector income and wealth: it’s a net leakage of disposable income from the nongovernment sector that reduces net saving and wealth by the same amount. When the government takes more from the public in taxes than it gives in spending, it
In defense of Obama's stimulus:
"These automatic stabilizers, not the bailouts or stimulus package, are the reason why the U.S. economy has not been in a free fall comparable to that of the Great Depression. When the economy slowed, the budget automatically went into a deficit, placing a floor under aggregate demand."
After reading this article, one highly theoretical argument that I can make is that if the United States was forced to monetize part of the debt it could raise interest on reserves to soak up any additional liquidity created in the system. This would represent a massive transfer of Government debt from the Treasury to the Fed in the form of excess reserves. The excess reserves could then be manipulated with the appropriate raising and lowering of the interest paid on reserves relative to the federal funds rate. This is quite an exciting premise that represents an internal transfer of funds by the U.S. Government that would keep inflation expectations stable while also calming the fears of deficit hawks.